ON THE BRINK OF RUNAWAY
INFLATION
The official monthly price
indexes (500% in January, 175% in February and 128% in March
on the wholesale market, and correspondingly 345%, 138%
and 130% on the retail market) are very optimistic for many
reasons and can be viewed as minimal. The Russian Statistics
Committee does not compute inflation indexes, but they are
close to consumer price indexes considering the "repressed
inflation".
How can one assess the economic
situation in a place where the monthly rate of inflation
has been expressed in two-digit figures for nearly six months
now?
Some books on economics describe
runaway inflation as a state of the economy in which prices
rise at a rate of more than 50% per month for an extended
period of time - six months or more. On the strength of
this definition, our situation is not yet runaway inflation.
But how justified are the hopes that prices will soon stop
growing?
Unfortunately, analysis shows
that the inflationary potential in the Russian economy today
is exceptionally high. Here we have practically every type
of inflation in the book.
Cost-push inflation. It was
caused by a number of factors.
First, the steep increase
in contract prices in January 1992 couldn't help but affect
prices on the other markets - the job and equipment markets,
etc. The February growth of population incomes (146.3%)
and of wholesale prices (175%) visibly outstripped the growth
of consumer prices (138%). That laid the basis for a further
increase in contract prices, and they began to climb in
late March. This is a typical cost-push inflation pattern
where the increase of cost and prices in certain economic
sectors bounces back at them with a gradually weakening
impact.
On the whole, this imbalance
was in evidence during the first three months of 1992: wholesale
prices were rising much faster than retail prices. If the
March price index is applied to December, the gap (according
to official statistics) was 2.2 times. At the same time,
the prices of fuel and energy resources were growing 33.7%
slower than retail prices. This signifies that the tremendous
pressure on retail prices can be attributed to growing costs
from industry in the absence of an energy price hike. It
is extremely difficult to contain such pressure.
Second, the new spiral in the
general increase of prices is pushing energy prices up.
In late April a decision was made to raise oil and gas prices
4.5-6.5 times. The government's forecast about retail prices
rising 50-75% is excessively optimistic. One can expect
a doubling or tripling of the prices of all goods and would
swing back to hit the oil and gas industry after a month
or two. This would predetermine yet another round of oil
and gas hikes.
Since consumption of energy
varies considerably from industry to industry and from region
to region, one of the first consequences of the freeing
of oil prices would be considerable disruption in the existing
sectoral and regional differences of prices and profits.
Attempts to right this imbalance would give a powerful impetus
to further price rises.
The government's objective
of matching the world oil prices as much as possible does
not take into account the fact that the Russian economy
has an entirely different structure, different and larger
amounts of energy resources and a material-intensive national
income. It follows that higher energy prices in our situation
would not only push up other prices but also affect production
volumes and the structure of consumption.
Finally, the big increases
in wages and pensions (from 342 to 800-900 roubles a month)
in May, as well as mounting strikes for still higher pay
started the classic race between prices and incomes which
is being thus far kept under control only by virtue of insufficient
cash supplies. As long as there is no wage indexation the
race will be kept in check. But it is obvious that further
yielding to social pressures is inevitable. The race will
obviously pick up speed step by step. Indeed, the absence
of wage indexation, which might control the speed of the
race, could result in an escalation of social demands.
The transition to a single
exchange rate for the rouble. The elimination of preferential
exchange rates would, on the one hand, sharply step up the
number of offers to commercial enterprises on the exchange
market, on the other, increase manifold the costs of enterprises
that traditionally depend on centralized imports (today
they buy raw materials and finished products at the rate
of 5.4 roubles per dollar).
The government's decision concerning
forms of subsidies - direct transfers from the budget for
these enterprises against providing subsidies, may have
different consequences on the rouble's free exchange rate,
the intensity of the inflationary pressure of costs on individual
commodity markets, as well as on bankruptcies and unemployment.
Direct subsidies for enterprises that depend on centralized
imports would put too heavy a burden on the budget. Most
likely, the government will opt for partial budgetary compensations
which would result in costs exerting an increasing pressure
on prices.
Demand inflation. As long
as there is a substantial budget deficit and too many loans
being issued, there will be a basis for growth in prices.
As shown above, this source of inflation have not been stemmed
completely.
All decisions on additional
state expenditures in conditions of the budget deficit can
breed inflation especially when the deficit - like Russia's
- is covered almost exclusively by issuing more money.
Ever widening divergences between
the domestic economic policies of the CIS countries, as
well as their resolve to issue their own currencies, appear
to intensify the influx of the rouble mass into Russia.
Tax-push inflation is on the
rise. It has become quite clear by now that contract prices
are high not only because of inflationary expectations,
but also because taxes are actually added to prices as production
costs. The situation is largely aggravated by the fact that
tax rates can hardly be reduced because of the critical
state of the Russian budget.
Finally, as world experience
shows, trying to bring prices into proper correlation causes
further overall growth of prices.
Thus the economy has a colossal
inflationary potential which remains, despite its soaking
up of the excess money supply and this potential will certainly
break loose in the coming months. It is being held up by
the shortage of a ready cash supply, but this is too weak
a barrier.
To all appearances inflation
in this country follows a peculiar pattern: price surges
between inflationary lulls.
In addition to purely quantitative
signs, there are important qualitative signals of the inflationary
state of the economy, and we can clearly distinguish them
today.
Steady inflationary expectations.
People in the USSR were first jolted out of their belief
that prices should remain unchanged in 1987 when the expediency
of raising retail prices was brought up. The people lived
through four periods of panic during the past two years
- May 1990 (USSR Premier Nikolai Ryzhkov announced a price
reform); January 1991 (exchange of large denominations);
the first three months of 1991 (expectation of the price
reform); and November-December 1991 (the Russian President
announced liberalization of prices). There were also constant
claims by Russia's new leaders that the rouble no longer
made any sense, that money reforms was inevitable, that
the economy could be stabilized with the help of inflation,
and that everything had collapsed one way or another, etc.
As a result, even the most stubborn rouble supporters were
no longer so sure.
The skyrocketing dollar exchange
rate when President Yeltsin announced reforms in October
1991 was a sure sign of a panicked demand for stable foreign
currency. The panicked buying in the expectation of the
promised price rise in two months' time was also obvious.
These behavioural stereotypes have not been broken by the
reform only because inflation has not been stopped. The
rather stable and widespread fleeing from the rouble is
a harsh reality.
So far these stereotypes are
true of current incomes. The first three months of the year
even registered some growth in savings banks deposits (this
is only an absolute rather than a relative growth). But
this growth can be attributed to a rumoured money reform
and transfers to Russia of rouble savings from the other
republics (because of the relatively less acute shortage
of cash in Russia and plans to introduce national currencies).
There is also a disturbing trend in savings banks deposits
which are failing from month to month. If it keeps up, the
net outflow of public savings will become a reality (this
is already taking place in a number of regions) and pose
serious problems to the Savings Bank and the budget which
relies on most of the bank's resources.
People now assess any sum
of money in terms of relatively stable foreign currencies,
and prices of goods and services can be quoted in Western
currencies. The supply of foreign currency inside Russia
is comparatively small to be giving rise to such a stereotype.
But the stereotype is being formed in big cities and primarily
in Moscow. Prices of many locally produced goods, that have
no chance of being sold abroad (Russian radio equipment,
apartments, many types of food, etc.) tend to be quoted
in dollars. The range of such goods is rather wide.
Changes in the credit market
structure. The volume of long-term (more than a year) investment
credits has plunged. An average loan term of today is 2-3
months.
While the list goes on, the
facts quoted so far are sufficient to realize that Russia
is on the brink of runaway inflation.
More than that, the door is
open and we are being irresistibly drawn in the direction.
With suppressed inflation of
demand the cost-push inflation would mount in every direction.
Far from decreasing, this pressure is growing compared with
its level at the start of the year.
Given this country's political
realities, the conclusion that the least. On the contrary,
runaway inflation is becoming inevitable.
|