FINANCIAL STABILIZATION
Simultaneously with the economy's
stabilization the government attempted to achieve financial
stabilization as early as the beginning of 1992.
The budget for the first quarter
of 1992 was presented to, and "taken note of," by the Russian
Federation's Supreme Soviet as being deficit-free. It was
expected to increase revenues by introducing a value added
tax and high export duties. Military spending, state investments
and social programmes were drastically cut in real terms.
However, the addendum to the government's February Memorandum
already spoke of a budgetary deficit expected to reach 15
percent of the GNP according to international methodology,
i.e. if some of the Ministry of Finance ruses (inclusion
of foreign credits in budgetary revenues, understatement
of Russia's share in liabilities on the internal debt of
the former USSR) were abolished.
The Central Bank of Russia
toughened its credit policy: gradually increasing reserve
demands in respect of commercial banks to 20 percent, raising
the rates on centralized credits from 2-9 percent to 20
and then 50 percent, and compounding the terms of centralized
crediting. The budgetary resources previously received by
former specialized banks and included in their authorized
funds were withdrawn from their accounts. These measures
resulted in a sharp rise in interest rates, an acute shortage
of credit resources and difficulties with keeping up the
balance for many commercial banks.
Besides the "classical" methods
of limiting the money mass, the government and Central Bank
of Russia also had recourse to "forbidden methods" by making
more frequent references to technical problems. This is
evidently linked to the fact that the government does not
have enough authority to pursue a tough fiscal policy. In
this connection mention should be made of the following:
1. The artificial deceleration
of clearings in the economy. The means of payment circulation
and the passage of clearings has been slowed by several
weeks in the past few months. In conditions of the crisis
of non-payment the Central Bank of Russia has decelerated
the conduct of clearings. The period between money being
written off of the customer's account and its being entered
on the seller's account now lasts several months. This has
considerably aggravated the financial problems of enterprises.
2. The cash crisis. For this
reason alone the debt to the population in respect to the
payment of wages, pensions and other incomes doubled in
Russia in the course of only one month to reach 40 billion
roubles on April 1. The situation in the other republics
(with the exception of Ukraine, which has adopted coupons)
is even graver. Delays with paying wages and other incomes
have become the norm. The distribution of ready money proper
is becoming an increasingly more significant lever of government
policy in its relations with the other republics and regions
inside Russia.
A problem which is easily prognosticated
and just as easily solved by the emission of large denomination
banknotes and the reduction of low-nominal clearings (for
example, the introduction of definite rules for rounding
up prices and incomes in the state sector and recommendations
for the same process in the private sector) has turned into
a powerful social irritant. It has compounded inter-republican
relations and stimulated the accelerated introduction of
national currencies by the other republics for the former
USSR, as well as the emission of various kinds of money
ersatzes inside Russia (in the framework of regions and
even individual enterprises). In other words, as an instrument
of policy the deficit of cash has generated so many new
problems that the government is overwhelmed by them.
3. The delay with officially
promised payments, especially in public health and educationcompensation
in connection with growing prices, the increase of pensions,
benefits, etc. threatens to paralyze budget-supported sectors,
which will intensify social tensions.
4. The patent violation of
legal succession on a number of the former federal state's
liabilities to the citizens and enterprises of Russia. The
freezing of the acceptance by savings banks of state loan
bonds and the internal currency liabilities of the USSR
Vnesheconombank, the abolition of the previously issued
licenses for export, the waves of enterprise re-registrations,
etc. This sharply lowers trust in the state and its commitments
to the population and entrepreneurs, which caused the return
in the first quarter of different kinds of state securities
to the total sum of 1.1 billion roubles. The accelerated
toughening of financial policy has resulted in real financial
restrictions for all enterprises and the population: the
prices leap has depreciated the money kept in bank accounts,
whereas the volumes of crediting and budgetary financing
tended to increase at a much slower pace than prices.
But no financial stabilization
has occurred.
The budgetary policy of the
first three months of 1992 suffered a fiasco. In Russia's
territory a mere 366 billion roubles was collected in state
revenue as against the original quarterly plan of 513 billion
roubles. There was a shortfall in the collection of value
added tax and excise duties, and the failure to reap the
revenues expected from foreign economic activities has already
been mentioned above.
The first incidences have
been registered of local authorities (in Bashkortostan,
Tatarstan, Chechnya, the Krasnodar Territory, etc.) refusing
to remit all the tax deduction envisaged by the law to the
republican budget. On the results of two months the sum
of money not remitted by local authorities is not so great
(8 percent for the tax on profit), yet the development of
this trend jeopardizes the unity and stability of the Russian
Federation's budgetary system, while speeding up the processes
of the state's disintegration.
Fundamental importance also
attaches to the sharp increase in the number and share of
exclusive government decisions in relation to individual
regions and enterprises, which must allegedly reduce discontent
with economic policy among the economically strongest and
soothe the more strident complaints (Surgut oil and gas
production association, Soyuzneftexport foreign trade association,
Mikhailovsky ore-dressing complex, Kuzbasrazrezugol concern).
Similar methods are also used
in the pursuit of social policy. The tactics of "petty"
concessions have so far made it possible to avoid mass strikes,
placing an ever heavier burden on the budget.
What enabled the government
to make a statement at the Congress about the minimum to
the tune of 1.5 percent of the GNP deficit of the state
budget on the results of the first quarter? This was possible
thanks to rather obvious arithmetical methods:
- the earnings and spendings involved in
foreign economic activities were excluded from the estimate
of the actual execution of the budget (there was transition
to taking stock of these activities solely on the balance).
It became impossible to collect the planned sums of export
duties;
- the government was unable to buy foreign
currency from exporters with which to pay the interest
on the foreign debt;
- there were very considerable delays
in the sale of currency earnings to the currency reserve.
As a result instead of the 2.9 billion dollars due to
be paid out in the first quarter after all deferments,
a mere 351 million US dollars (or under 12 percent) were
paid out as of March 6. Undoubtedly, the fulfillment of
Russia's foreign liabilities would have sharply boosted
budgetary expenditures (even under the Central Bank of
Russia's special exchange rate of 55 roubles per dollar
2.5 billion dollars mean a budget deficit as high as 140
billion roubles);
- as before foreign credits are taken
into account in budgetary revenues;
- a significant part of the already revised
expenditures of the first quarter nearly 46 billion roubles
was "transferred" to April, which temporarily produced
a favourable picture but is bound to show in the results
of the second quarter;
- the nature and terms of the "loan" of
some 30 billion roubles borrowed by the Russian Ministry
of Finance from local budgets, making it possible to minimize
the actual sum of the deficit, are not clear.
Statements by the leaders
of the government and the Ministry of Finance of the Russian
Federation on the budget for the first quarter of 1992 cannot
but evoke mistrust after the appearance of at least four
different official documents containing data which significantly
differ from one another: the government's budgetary messages
to the Supreme Soviet dated January 14, March 10 and April
29, 1992, the Law "On the budgetary system of the Russian
Federation in the first quarter of 1992", the Memorandum
"On economic policy", and the government's Resolution No.
169 on March 17, 1992.
The Central Bank's credits
are used as before to f budget deficit. It cannot be hoped
to place state securities among the population because,
having discontinued circulation of 1982 state internal loan
bonds, the government has intensified the people's mistrust
in all state securities, thus compounding the flotation
of fresh loans.
Orientation towards overcoming
the budgetary deficit at an accelerated rate has intensified
production recession (this tends to undermine the revenue
basis of the budget) and triggered an escalation of social
demands. It is safe to forecast an increase in the relative
size of the state budget deficit in the second quarter of
1992 in comparison with the first.
Despite its firm statements
the government has been unable to keep up the course it
adopted towards limiting credits.
The issue of 83 billion roubles
worth of loans in January was three times that of the December
level. Loan investments during the month increased 17.6%,
or three times as much as was planned. By the end of February
Central Bank loans to commercial banks were up 40% over
the figure at the start of the year, whereas they were originally
expected to rise 15% in just three months.
The proposed sought loan policy
was violated in many respects:
- The Central Bank of Russia advanced
loans (at 50% and then at 100% annual interest) for the
left-side balance of commercial banks, thereby making
them confident that this sort of approach will naturally
continue in the future.
- The Central Bank of Russia advanced
special-purpose loans worth 36 billion roubles to agricultural
enterprises and timber and oil industries, and this provoked
a stream of similar demands from other types of enterprises.
- Despite the stage-by-stage increase
in the interest rate, it is still negligible given the
present rate of inflation which means that the loans are
simply being "given away".
The decision made early in
April to issue additional centralized loans worth 200 billion
roubles only confirmed the government's reneging on its
pledge to severely limit the amount of money in circulation.
The slackening in the financial
policy immediately resulted in an increase in the issue
of money. Whereas in January it fell to a third of December's
(down to 17 billion roubles), in February it reached 24
billion roubles, and in March 37 billion roubles. The sum
of money the state failed to pay in the form of wages, salaries,
pensions and benefits was worth more than a monthly issue
of money.
The government regards the
increase and later relative stabilization of the rouble's
exchange rate at the exchange market as one key sign of
success of its macroeconomic policy.
In our view the main reason
for the increase in the rouble rate wasn't the Russian government's
financial policy, albeit it was important. Let's consider
the facts. Prompted by panic, the rouble rate plunged during
October 1991 - January 1992 from 70 to 230 against the dollar.
The exchange market was pervaded by panic in late January
1992 with prices out of control. The Central Bank off Russia
and the government launched a propaganda campaign whereby
a number of officials made statements about an imminent
increase in the rouble's exchange rate to 35-50 against
the dollar. Following this, the Bank sharply stepped up
its sale of hard currency at the Inter-Bank Currency Market
(IBCM), and sold 3-4 and, later, up to 15 million dollars
at each competitive trading session. The various technical
restrictions on demand for roubles at the IBCM, including
restricted participation at auctions, permit a wide manipulation
of the rate of exchange. Increases in the rouble exchange
rate are not matched with the dynamics of main macroeconomic
factors; thus they are artificial, and therefore can only
be temporary. This is a stability sustained by hard currency
interventions of the Central Bank of Russia whilst Russia
fails to honour its commitment to other countries. This
playing at all's well will continue as long as our creditors
- the governments and banks of industrialized countries
continue to shut their eyes to this dubious operation.
All that indicates that the
rouble exchange rate may plummet at any moment. This can
be provoked by a high inflation rate, a rise in fears that
inflation will rise further in connection with the jump
in energy costs, substantial cuts in the size of hard currency
interventions by the Central Bank of Russia, as well as
buyer's "overcoming" of the artificial restrictions on buying
hard currency. No real stabilization of the exchange rate
seems to be in sight because it continues to experience
too powerful an impact from such divergent factors as the
expectation of a money reform, introduction in the "rouble
zone" of other national currencies, the bringing into play
of the six-billion fund (to stabilize the rouble) as promised
by the G7 industrialized countries.
Thus the government has practically
fallen short of its objective to achieve fast financial
stabilization. Worse than that, the inflation rate during
February-April was greater than it was October-November
1991. According to the Committee for Statistics of the Russian
Federation, following the 3.5-times price hike in consumer
goods, retail prices went up 24% further in February and
21% in March. While sale price indexes were correspondingly
500, 175 and 128 percent. Independent experts think that
the real level of inflation is 1.5-2 times greater. The
government promised to bring inflation down to 3-5 percent
per month at the end of the first quarter of this year.
One has to admit that THE
GOVERNMENT'S FINANCIAL POLICY, WHICH WAS THE PRINCIPAL AND
VERY NEARLY THE ONLY POLITICAL LINE CONSCIOUSLY AND PURPOSEFULLY
PURSUED BY THE RUSSIAN GOVERNMENT, HAS SUFFERED A SETBACK.
|